AGL 38.02 Increased By ▲ 0.08 (0.21%)
AIRLINK 197.36 Increased By ▲ 3.45 (1.78%)
BOP 9.54 Increased By ▲ 0.22 (2.36%)
CNERGY 5.91 Increased By ▲ 0.07 (1.2%)
DCL 8.82 Increased By ▲ 0.14 (1.61%)
DFML 35.74 Decreased By ▼ -0.72 (-1.97%)
DGKC 96.86 Increased By ▲ 4.32 (4.67%)
FCCL 35.25 Increased By ▲ 1.28 (3.77%)
FFBL 88.94 Increased By ▲ 6.64 (8.07%)
FFL 13.17 Increased By ▲ 0.42 (3.29%)
HUBC 127.55 Increased By ▲ 6.94 (5.75%)
HUMNL 13.50 Decreased By ▼ -0.10 (-0.74%)
KEL 5.32 Increased By ▲ 0.10 (1.92%)
KOSM 7.00 Increased By ▲ 0.48 (7.36%)
MLCF 44.70 Increased By ▲ 2.59 (6.15%)
NBP 61.42 Increased By ▲ 1.61 (2.69%)
OGDC 214.67 Increased By ▲ 3.50 (1.66%)
PAEL 38.79 Increased By ▲ 1.21 (3.22%)
PIBTL 8.25 Increased By ▲ 0.18 (2.23%)
PPL 193.08 Increased By ▲ 2.76 (1.45%)
PRL 38.66 Increased By ▲ 0.49 (1.28%)
PTC 25.80 Increased By ▲ 2.35 (10.02%)
SEARL 103.60 Increased By ▲ 5.66 (5.78%)
TELE 8.30 Increased By ▲ 0.08 (0.97%)
TOMCL 35.00 Decreased By ▼ -0.03 (-0.09%)
TPLP 13.30 Decreased By ▼ -0.25 (-1.85%)
TREET 22.16 Decreased By ▼ -0.57 (-2.51%)
TRG 55.59 Increased By ▲ 2.72 (5.14%)
UNITY 32.97 Increased By ▲ 0.01 (0.03%)
WTL 1.60 Increased By ▲ 0.08 (5.26%)
BR100 11,727 Increased By 342.7 (3.01%)
BR30 36,377 Increased By 1165.1 (3.31%)
KSE100 109,513 Increased By 3238.2 (3.05%)
KSE30 34,513 Increased By 1160.1 (3.48%)

ARTICLE: Dr Ishrat Husain had described the decade of the 1990s as a 'lost decade' for Pakistan. For this writer, however, the decade of 2008-18 was yet another lost decade for Pakistan. It is unfortunate that a country like Pakistan experienced two decades of lost economic opportunities in its seven decades of existence.

The second lost decade (2008-18) witnessed economic growth slowing to an average of 3.8 percent per annum at the back of declining public and private sector investment. In fact, this decade made 3.5-4.0 percent economic growth a new normal for Pakistan, resulting in slower job creation and rising unemployment.

This decade also witnessed perpetuation of fiscal indiscipline, resulting in growing fiscal deficit and rising public and external debt and liabilities. While the decade of the 1990s added $17.4 billion in external debt and liabilities, the second lost decade (2008-18) added over $55 billion to the same. These two lost decades therefore, added $72.4 billion or over 75 percent to the outstanding stock of external debt and liabilities as of end-June 2018. Alarmingly, over three-fourth of $95.2 billion debt and liabilities as of end-June 2018 were accumulated during the two lost decades, more so in the second lost decade.

This decade also witnessed massive deterioration of Institutions. In particular, Institutions dealing with economic policy witnessed massive erosion of professional capacity which compelled successive governments to rely on "consultants". Weakening of Institutions also eroded policy-making ability of governments, resulting in excessive reliance on donors for policy formulation.

Against the backdrop of the second lost decade, came the present government at the helm of affairs. The present leadership, while in opposition, raised enormous expectations of the people of Pakistan. There are no two opinions that the present government had inherited an economy that was really in a bad shape. Current account deficit was at an all-time high at $20 billion in 2017-18, budget deficit (excluding circular debt expenditure) was as high as 6.6 percent of GDP, economic growth was slowing and unemployment was rising. It was indeed a gigantic task for the new government to address the multidimensional challenges. There is a general consensus among independent economists that instead of addressing humongous challenges that it inherited, the inexperienced economic team further compounded the difficulties.

The government either had no option but to seek a balance of payments support from the IMF or was "forced" to go to the IMF for a 22nd IMF Program. In either case, the government went to the IMF for balance of payments support. It was an interesting coincident that the present leadership came to power after 22 years of continuous struggle only to land up in the 22nd IMF Program.

It is essential for the readers to know the mindset of the IMF as an institution. The intellectual philosophy of this Institution is based on the Chicago School of Thought, that is, everything is a monetary phenomenon; balance of payments is a monetary phenomenon caused by excessive demand in the economy and that inflation is also a monetary phenomenon, again caused by the excess of demand over supply of goods. The excessive demand is caused by "too much money chasing too few goods".

Based on this philosophy, the standard IMF prescription is geared towards addressing the issue of excessive demand. That is why the IMF Program is known as demand management/demand destruction/austerity Program. The standard prescription to manage demand dates back to the early 1980s and enshrined in the so called stabilization policy. While the world has changed in the last four decades, the prescription of the IMF has remained unchanged.

For managing demand, the standard IMF prescription of the 1980s included: a) tight monetary policy; b) tight fiscal policy; c) market-based exchange rate regime; and d) adjusting utility prices. The previous 21 IMF programmes had rested on these four policy prescriptions; the current Program is once again based on the same four policy prescriptions. How these policy prescriptions work to curtail aggregate demand (after all, it is a demand management program)? Firstly, through tightening of monetary policy, that is, raising discount rate as fast as possible. Since discount rate serves as a benchmark for all the lending rates, private sector investment declines which, in turn, reduces import demand. Since developing countries economic activity depend principally on imported raw materials, imported capital goods, imported machinery and equipment, and imported energy, any decline in imports slows down the economic activity. In other words, demand destruction is achieved by chocking the economic activities of the country.

How else can we discourage imports, promote exports and, hence reduce current account imbalances? Very simple! Go for massive devaluation. Devaluation increases the landed cost of all the imported items including inputs to the production process. Higher cost of imported items not only discourage its consumption but also increases the cost of production. Hence, lower import slows economic growth. Since devaluation is also inflationary by definition, the Central Bank justifies tightening of monetary policy (i.e., raising discount rate) to contain inflationary pressures.

Higher interest rate, on the other hand, increases cost of borrowing of the government to finance fiscal deficit and therefore, increases interest payment. In the absence of commensurate rise in revenue, the overall fiscal deficit increases. Hence, an irrelevant tax target is given under the IMF program to achieve targeted fiscal deficit. The government is also being asked to raise utility prices, supposedly to improve the financial health of the utility companies, but actually it also increases the cost of production.

The entire focus of the program is therefore on increasing the cost of production to make the industry non-competitive in international market as well as raising public debt. Higher interest rate increases cost of capital; devaluation increases cost of imported inputs; higher utility prices (gas, electricity) increases cost of production and irrelevant revenue target further burdened the industry with tax incidence. Devaluation accompanied by higher interest rate drowns the country into debt.

In this article, this writer intends to present the impact of only two policy prescriptions of the current IMF programme. One deals with discount rate because we have been told time and again that this rate is increased to counter inflationary pressure. The other deals with devaluation because we have been told time and again that this will improve the competitiveness of our industry and exports will increase to correct external imbalances. Let us see whether these policies have historically worked to achieve the desired results.

1) Discount rate and inflation

As stated above, we have been repeatedly told that the SBP has increased the discount rate to control inflation. In other words, there is an inverse relationship between discount rate and inflation. A cursory look at Fig. 1 is sufficient to see a strong positive relationship between the two variables. The graph shows that whenever discount rate is raised, the CPI-based inflation rises accordingly. As stated, earlier, interest rate is a cost of capital. When it is raised, the cost of borrowing goes up and accordingly, it is passed on to the consumers.

The Governor SBP had stated several times during the release of monetary policy statement that inflation in Pakistan is a supply side phenomenon followed by the rise of government administered prices (prices of gas, electricity etc.) and yet he continued to use the demand side instrument (discount rate) to contain inflation. He failed to see the composition of the CPI-basket where almost 35 percent contribution comes from food items followed by the prices of gas, electricity, fuel, water and house rent (24%). House rent is measured through the quarterly survey of the housing units for rent purpose. Transport charges are linked with fuel prices and it accounts for almost 6 percent weight to the CPI. Prices of medicines are largely controlled by the government (2.8%)Schools are not free to charge tuition fee (education) of their likings (3.8%). Thus, almost three-fourth of the CPI basket are not affected by discount rate at all and yet our Central Bank continued to use this instrument to control inflation. This misconstrued policy alone added Rs 1,687 billion to interest payment during July 2018 till March 2020. It has simply eroded fiscal space, contributed immensely in widening fiscal deficit and raising public debt.

The high interest rate policy on the other hand attracted "Hot Money" in our short-term Treasury Bills, that was immensely beneficial for foreigners and damaging for the local economy. The high interest policy attracted "Hot Money" by putting the domestic economy in cold storage. High interest rate policy certainly did not reduce inflation but it contributed to the rise in interest payments, deterioration in fiscal balance, addition to public debt, reducing investment, slowing economic growth, rising unemployment and poverty, reducing tax collection and so on. Who is responsible for this damage to the economy?

2) Export and exchange rate

We have been told by the SBP and its ill-informed Governor that devaluation would improve the competiveness of our industry abroad and hence would help increase exports. A cursory look at Fig. 2 is sufficient to see that our exports have remained invariant to the adjustment ofexchange rate. This graph covers over 100 months of exports and exchange rate numbers.It is clear that our exports have moved in a narrow monthly range of $1.7 billion to $2.3 billion, irrespective of exchange rate, whether it is Rs. 60 per dollar or Rs. 160 per dollar. I have been arguing time and again that by adjusting exchange rate Pakistan cannot increase its exports. Devaluation raises input cost of export-oriented industries and makes them non-competitive. According to Dr Ishrat Husain, close to 60 percent inputs of export-oriented industries are imported, hence devaluation raises their costs and renders them non-competitive. While devaluation failed to increase exports, it certainly added Rs 4,666 billion to public debt without borrowing a single dollar during July 2018 to March 2020.

These two policies have cost Pakistan Rs 6,353 billion or approximately $40 billion for a $6 billion IMF programme. Who is responsible for this damage? The readers would recall that myself and other saner economists of this country were crying every day that this high interest rate policy would damage Pakistan's economy. No one including the Prime Minister listened to us. Who has paid the price of this misconstrued policy? Naturally, this government and the people of Pakistan.

On exchange rate policy, I have been telling the people of Pakistan through electronic media that devaluation would not increase exports. It will simply add to public debt. My views, were based on personal experience that I gained during eleven years of my stay in the Ministry of Finance. I was glad that Dr Ishrat Husain, a former Governor of the SBP also came to the same conclusion.

Once again, nobody listened to us. The PTI government has added almost Rs 4,666 billion to the public debt because of the devaluation without raising exports. The Prime Minister and others never bothered to get alternative views. The nation has paid a heavy price of these misconstrued policies. People who descended on the scene by helicopter had little or no idea about the statistics of Pakistan. They have never studied Pakistan's economy. They brought the knowledge of the western economies and their policies and brutally implemented the same in a developing country like Pakistan. Such policies have severely damaged the economy, dented the popularity of the Prime Minister and put the government on the back foot, trying to hide behind inheritance. Interestingly, the Prime Minister on the other hand has collected the failed policies and players of the 2nd lost decade to build Pakistan's economy. Good luck to the Prime Minister.

(The writer is Principal & Dean of the School of Social Sciences & Humanities (S3H), NUST, Islamabad and can be reached at [email protected])

Copyright Business Recorder, 2020

Comments

Comments are closed.