AGL 37.94 Increased By ▲ 0.09 (0.24%)
AIRLINK 155.22 Increased By ▲ 12.75 (8.95%)
BOP 9.07 Increased By ▲ 0.06 (0.67%)
CNERGY 6.72 Increased By ▲ 1.00 (17.48%)
DCL 9.53 Increased By ▲ 0.29 (3.14%)
DFML 40.31 Increased By ▲ 0.87 (2.21%)
DGKC 92.95 Increased By ▲ 3.64 (4.08%)
FCCL 38.38 Decreased By ▼ -0.16 (-0.42%)
FFBL 78.58 Increased By ▲ 1.14 (1.47%)
FFL 13.60 Decreased By ▼ -0.02 (-0.15%)
HUBC 110.19 Increased By ▲ 0.90 (0.82%)
HUMNL 14.89 Decreased By ▼ -0.24 (-1.59%)
KEL 5.73 Decreased By ▼ -0.05 (-0.87%)
KOSM 8.47 Increased By ▲ 0.27 (3.29%)
MLCF 45.66 Increased By ▲ 1.13 (2.54%)
NBP 76.17 Increased By ▲ 2.55 (3.46%)
OGDC 191.87 Increased By ▲ 0.11 (0.06%)
PAEL 30.48 Increased By ▲ 2.77 (10%)
PIBTL 8.16 Increased By ▲ 0.17 (2.13%)
PPL 166.56 Decreased By ▼ -0.61 (-0.36%)
PRL 29.44 Increased By ▲ 2.61 (9.73%)
PTC 20.07 Decreased By ▼ -0.62 (-3%)
SEARL 96.62 Decreased By ▼ -0.91 (-0.93%)
TELE 8.27 Increased By ▲ 0.06 (0.73%)
TOMCL 34.26 Decreased By ▼ -0.74 (-2.11%)
TPLP 10.22 Increased By ▲ 0.32 (3.23%)
TREET 17.66 Increased By ▲ 0.31 (1.79%)
TRG 61.25 Increased By ▲ 0.25 (0.41%)
UNITY 31.97 Increased By ▲ 0.33 (1.04%)
WTL 1.47 Increased By ▲ 0.01 (0.68%)
BR100 11,216 Increased By 119.9 (1.08%)
BR30 33,650 Increased By 395.8 (1.19%)
KSE100 104,559 Increased By 1284.1 (1.24%)
KSE30 32,366 Increased By 396.5 (1.24%)

“There are no solutions. There are only trade-offs.” ? Thomas Sowell Nomura has warned that Pakistan faces currency crisis danger. How should Pakistan deal with a potential currency crisis - if it did occur? Firstly, it is important to understand that a currency crisis is when a weak currency (in this case the PKR) depreciates significantly as a result of selling.

Since the 1990s, most currency crises have involved balance sheet effects: a country (either public or private sector, or both) has large external liabilities in foreign currency. In that case depreciation worsens balance sheets, creating a self-reinforcing downward spiral. That was the story for Asia in the 90s, the Argentine crisis 2001, part of the problem in Pakistan now.

Economists identified some common characteristics that caused the crisis after the dust settled in Asia: The region’s currencies were overvalued; economies were over reliant on short-term borrowing from foreign lenders; private banks and finance companies were fragile and weakly regulated; and governments lacked the necessary political consensus needed to take swift and painful measures to adjust and stabilise the economy.

Valuable lessons can be learned from the exchange rate, monetary, and fiscal responses to the recent currency crises in Asia and Latin America. Policy tradeoffs in response to speculative attacks are grim.

No matter what governments do, the costs are high. The less costly response to a speculative attack depends on the nature of the shock, the economy’s initial conditions, and the balance sheets of banks, firms, and the government. In general.

Allowing the exchange rate to float

If you peg your exchange rate at a too-high level, you’re setting your country up for disaster, because any decline in the exchange rate will be sudden and catastrophic instead of slow and gradual.

Slow and gradual declines give a country time to reverse course and fix whatever factors are driving down the exchange rate. A sudden collapse gives you no time at all.

Thus, exchange rate pegs are very risky. Such a sudden collapse for Pakistan will bring another round of inflation for Pakistan. Given Pakistan already has an inflation rate of 27%, such a sudden collapse of the PKR could bring about a rapid increase in inflation as it did for Sri Lanka earlier this year for up to 50% (see graph).

Monetary policy

Adoption of a flexible exchange rate regime will impose the need for a new monetary framework and a new nominal anchor. If a country does not have the preconditions for inflation targeting, the central bank can use a combination of instruments to create a new monetary framework.

The framework can include the standard elements of ceilings on net domestic assets and floors on net international reserves. These limits must be consistent with the use of reserves to meet current account needs.

To keep inflation and exchange rate depreciation in check, the central bank will have to tightly constrain the implicit expansion of base money (money supply).The most difficult problem is setting monetary policy during the first few weeks following the collapse of the exchange rate, when financial market conditions and expectations are likely to remain unsettled. Trying to run monetary policy by targeting a monetary aggregate works poorly on a day-to-day basis.

The substantial depreciation of the currency after a speculative attack implies that during the months following the collapse of the currency, inflation can increase sharply (as a result of one-time adjustments in many prices).

This temporary increase in inflation implies a substantial reduction in real interest rates on debt denominated in domestic currency. To offset, at least partially, this near-term effect, it is appropriate for policymakers to raise nominal interest rates temporarily to avoid further depreciation and the danger of igniting a spiral of depreciation and inflation.

Fiscal policy

A new exchange rate will be sustainable only if it is perceived to be fiscally responsible. For this reason, speculative crises need to be followed by restrictive fiscal policies. But fiscal policy should not be too contractionary.

If interest rates are kept high to avoid speculation and inflation following the collapse of the exchange rate, policymakers may want to avoid excessive expenditure cuts, which could lead to more contraction and lower tax revenues, making it more difficult to service the public debt.

Sufficient time must be given to achieve the goal of moving the debt/GDP ratio to a sustainable level. A program that attempts to force the convergence of the debt/GDP ratio to its desirable long-run level too quickly could fail to achieve its goals, thereby reducing the policymaker’s credibility.

Credibility will be enhanced if fiscal reform is perceived to be sustainable and leading to fiscal balance in the medium run rather than based on unsustainable expenditure cuts and tax increases in the near run.

Copyright Business Recorder, 2023

Muneeb Sikander

The writer is an economist and strategy consultant. He is also functioning in an advisory capacity for the London School of Economics Lean Launchpad and serving on the board of two global think-tanks, GAIEI and IGOAI

Twitter: @MuneebASikander

Email: muneebsikander@ hotmail.com

Comments

Comments are closed.

Adam Hussain Jan 10, 2023 03:53am
Great article Muneeb. Part of the problem with Pakistan is the huge amount of corruption, stiffer sentencing is needed in order to totally eliminate corruption. With a vast Pakistani diaspora all over the World, Pakistanis are helping to support the PKR by buy the PKR in exchange for £ Sterling, $ USD, etc After independence India has managed to develop at a much faster rate than Pakistan, why? Yes they have corruption to, but much less, their government has invested heavily in its education systems, and there is a better balance between private and public sectors. Pakistan is blessed with the Sun, the government needs to invest in solar power, ALL new developments should have at least 60% + of renewal energy, solar electricity stored in domestic batteries, solar panels above all shopping centers. If there is zero element of renewable energy the development should be declined. Invest in solar, renewal energy etc with a view to the export markets, thus earning valuable foreign exchange, and supporting the PKR.
thumb_up Recommended (0)