AGL 37.94 No Change ▼ 0.00 (0%)
AIRLINK 160.75 Increased By ▲ 5.53 (3.56%)
BOP 8.97 Decreased By ▼ -0.10 (-1.1%)
CNERGY 6.77 Increased By ▲ 0.05 (0.74%)
DCL 10.04 Increased By ▲ 0.51 (5.35%)
DFML 40.49 Increased By ▲ 0.18 (0.45%)
DGKC 91.60 Decreased By ▼ -1.35 (-1.45%)
FCCL 37.80 Decreased By ▼ -0.58 (-1.51%)
FFBL 78.45 Decreased By ▼ -0.13 (-0.17%)
FFL 13.45 Decreased By ▼ -0.15 (-1.1%)
HUBC 113.12 Increased By ▲ 2.93 (2.66%)
HUMNL 14.55 Decreased By ▼ -0.34 (-2.28%)
KEL 5.63 Decreased By ▼ -0.10 (-1.75%)
KOSM 8.18 Decreased By ▼ -0.29 (-3.42%)
MLCF 44.55 Decreased By ▼ -1.11 (-2.43%)
NBP 74.99 Decreased By ▼ -1.18 (-1.55%)
OGDC 192.25 Increased By ▲ 0.38 (0.2%)
PAEL 31.61 Increased By ▲ 1.13 (3.71%)
PIBTL 8.38 Increased By ▲ 0.22 (2.7%)
PPL 166.98 Increased By ▲ 0.42 (0.25%)
PRL 31.33 Increased By ▲ 1.89 (6.42%)
PTC 22.08 Increased By ▲ 2.01 (10.01%)
SEARL 96.90 Increased By ▲ 0.28 (0.29%)
TELE 8.53 Increased By ▲ 0.26 (3.14%)
TOMCL 34.45 Increased By ▲ 0.19 (0.55%)
TPLP 11.10 Increased By ▲ 0.88 (8.61%)
TREET 18.00 Increased By ▲ 0.34 (1.93%)
TRG 60.76 Decreased By ▼ -0.49 (-0.8%)
UNITY 32.20 Increased By ▲ 0.23 (0.72%)
WTL 1.52 Increased By ▲ 0.05 (3.4%)
BR100 11,220 Increased By 3.7 (0.03%)
BR30 33,847 Increased By 196.2 (0.58%)
KSE100 104,697 Increased By 137.7 (0.13%)
KSE30 32,392 Increased By 25.8 (0.08%)

Since there are both demand pull and cost-push factors influencing inflation it is not possible to manage inflation through just one/two policy instruments-especially when one instrument, the interest rate, is expected to achieve multiple objectives. The reason is that the sources of demand in the economy are households, corporate sector and government, who in turn receive money from different sources.

The role of each source and what can be done about it is somewhat limited, especially because the acts of one can nullify the actions of others, at times as a result of unanticipated developments. For example, when the State Bank of Pakistan (SBP) increases the interest rate it expects a change in behaviour of the borrower. However, if the largest borrower, government, continues borrowing to finance expenditures which are (except on development projects, politically inelastic in the short to medium term) more than its revenues it negates the objective of raising the interest-rate.

Then there are inflows of remittances and donor financial assistance which create additional demand for goods and services that render policy instruments for containing demand redundant. Again, SBP's own sponsored export finance and long-term directed credit schemes at highly concessional rates of interest (compared with the Policy Rate) 'create money', diluting the impact of its monetary policy instruments to control inflation. And, not to forget, we have a significantly large informal sector that conducts transactions mostly in cash (currency-in-circulation is currently in excess of Rs.5.5 trillion, 12.5% of GDP), on which adjustments in interest rates would have limited impact.

The effectiveness of SBP's policy to 'target' some rate/range of inflation is constrained by the structural nature of the problems. Monetary policy instruments have limitations. For example, an increase in the interest rate cannot fight imported or food inflation when the latter is high because a) the support price of wheat is above its international price; b) increases in price of energy and oil raise the cost of farming, processing and transportation; c) yields per acre of crops' continue to be low and d) of hoarding, and cartelization.

Similarly, there are cost-push factors affecting large areas of the economy resulting from a) rigidities in prices administered by government (e.g. of electricity, gas, etc.); b) poor governance adding to costs; c)a tax structure that is heavily dependent on high rates of GST and other indirect taxes; and d) powerful cartels manipulating prices. These prices are not affected by weakening in demand for goods and services and the profligacy of government that keeps budget deficits high-whose financing raises the interest rate on borrowings and tends to crowd out the private sector seeking funds for investment.

It is factors like these that make it difficult to handle inflation. For instance, addressing food inflation requires a comprehensive policy package comprising policies that incentivize increase in yields and cost efficiencies in production processes and an open trade policy to counter cartel formation, measures beyond the scope of monetary policy. Increasing interest rates cannot tackle revisions in government administered prices or inflation fed by rupee inflation and rising food prices. The stubbornness of a high rate of inflation in a relatively depressed economy translating into a wage-price spiral would be remote if the rate of economic growth is lower than the rate of increase in the labour force.

Other key factors in keeping inflation higher inflation have been continuing poor productivity (failure to get higher output from existing resources) and investment in un-productive schemes or projects that have stalled.

Furthermore, simply pursing single mindedly the goal of checking inflation can adversely impact growth and employment creation. The SBP does not have an adequate set of policy instruments in its armour to stimulate growth, lower the rate of inflation and ensure stability of the exchange rate, all at the same time. Moreover, inflation targeting has not been adopted as the sole objective by all central banks? Two economic power houses, China and USA, are seemingly not merely targeting inflation.

Admittedly, a sharp decline in inflows of external capital may warrant high rates of interest a) to check switching of portfolios (depositors switching from rupees to dollars-expecting the rupee to depreciate at a rate faster than interest rate on rupee deposits); and b) to incentivize foreign inflows (as has been one of the arguments for jacking up interest rates) which apart from appreciating the exchange rate, can, in turn, worsen the adverse movement in the domestic business cycle, discouraging investment by making capital expensive.

The internal and external imbalances of advanced economies can be addressed simultaneously. They can afford the luxury of printing currencies, because their currencies can be freely converted and traded in international financial markets. In other words, they can conduct their monetary policy freely to meet the requirements of the domestic business cycle. The currencies of developing countries, on the other hand, are not freely convertible and tradable. These economies need capital inflows and donor support to maintain foreign exchange reserves in tradable currencies to enable them to face any crises in financing external obligations. In our case, external payment crises require bail outs by the IMF and other multilateral and bilateral donors and 'special friends' like the Chinese, Saudis and the Emirates.

Although, a variety of import curbing policies and instruments are presently in place, the Pak rupee is supposedly 'free floating' when it comes to trade in goods and services as well as on the 'capital account' (the latter essentially for non-residents). Any restriction on bringing in and repatriating foreign capital will make the external investors reluctant to bring in this money. And reliance on large inflows of borrowed capital on a continuous basis is clearly not sustainable. Pakistan's experience to date confirms that it enlarges these imbalances overtime, creating conditions for external payment crises. The threat of such crises has forced us to opt for a monetary policy instrument, a higher interest rate, to tackle external crises, an intervention more likely to fail.

Copyright Business Recorder, 2020

Comments

Comments are closed.